Trade Policy and Efficiency:
Aggregate cross sectironal analysis does not reveal the channels through which trade policy might affect economic performance. Detailed analysis of the impact of trade and industrial policy was undertaken in two major projects. The results of the two studies are surnmarised in Little, Scitovsky and Skott (1970), Bhagwati (1978), and Krueger (1978). Their conclusions were some-
what similar in that the countries following more open export oriented policies and using the market mechanism rather than quantitative controls had performed better.
We follow the discussion in Bhagwati, as this is a detailed analysis of the working of trade and industrial policies. Bhagwati argued that the operation of a QR regime resulted in iriefficiencies, as the lack of sufficient relevant economic information resulted in the allocation of licenses among the many alternative users on the basis of some notion of equity rather than on the basis of economic costs and benefits. For instance, licenses for the import of raw materials were often allocated proportionately to installed capacity. Since the output of efficient firms was limited, there would be a demand for the output of inefficient firms, who would also receive their share of licenses. Bhagwati also argued that an efficient firm might get additional imported inputs for larger production only by expanding capacity, even though it may have under-utilised capacity. Bhagwati identified the major static inefficiencies as excess holding of inventories, capacity undemtilisation, the choice of inappropriate techniques of production of due to distorted factor prices, and inefficient allocation of investment.
But the evidence is mixed as the quantitative controls system may itself frustrate the achievement of the allocations desired by economic agents in response to the incentives created by the system. For instance, the granting of licenses may take time, so producers may desire to hold excess inventories of imported intermediates. But licenses for sufficient imports to hold the excess inventories may not be granted, so the actual level of inventories may not reach the desired level above the normal level of inventories. Also, other factors might explain the excess inventories. Though Turkey, which had a restrictive regime had a high mtio of inventories, Chile, which also had a restrictive regime, had a lower ratio than Japan and Spain and a ratio only slightly higher than in Franqe and the USA.
The experience of most countries which have liberalised would bear out the conclusion that the existing industries were not very inefficient. The lack of bankruptcies on a large scale in most liberalisation episodes except Chile would suggest that industries established during the protectionist period were not very inefficient and, given a few years to adjust, were able to meet international competition. The relationship between efficient industries and export performance may be even more tenuous, as was argued above. Even if a consumer industry in an LDC is eficient, if it is owned by a transnational the parent company might prefer to export from its home plants. For instance, the General Motors subsidiary in Korea, Daewoo, did not export, unlike the domestically owned firm Hyundai, despite the same policy environment. Exports of capital goods industries might also be constrained by the inability of LDCs to grant credit.