Recent arguments on free trade policy:
A few decades back, the comparative performances of the Latin American and East Asian economies showed that the latter had not only outpaced their Latin American counterparts but had also been able to withstand external shocks while maintaining their growth performances over a considerable span of time. With limits of domestic markets emerging as impediments to growth in the East Asia and Latin America, the experiences of these countries were used to argue that import-substituting policies had failed and should be replaced by export-promotion which was supposed to achieve faster growth than import substituting strategy.
It was argued that the import-substituting regimes of the developing countries had resulted in low growth equilibrium, characterised by inefficient allocation of resources, artificial rents and parallel markets. It was also suggested that in the absence of global competition, protected domestic enterprises were com- promising on efficiency concerns that resulted in availability of poor quality goods at unduly higher prices. Absence of the pressures of competition was also making these protected enterprises as less-enterprising and less- innovative. Thus, there was a need to aim at economic openness and in this context trade openness was considered as a tool for bringing economic development through export-led growth and consequent employment generation.
For developing countries, globalisation offers access to foreign capital, global export markets, and advanced technology while breaking the monopoly of inefficient and protected domestic producers. Faster growth, in turn, promotes poverty reduction, democratisation, and higher labour and environmental standards.
These arguments and global developments generally have strengthened the case for an open trading system. It is held that the historical record is very clear that free trade bestows many benefits. Those countries that lower trade barriers and open their markets enjoy higher economic standards of living. Consumers have access to a wider range of higher quality products at prices lower than they would otherwise pay if they were forced to buy them from domestic producers. The average person also benefits in terms ofwages and job opportunities. When labour and capital flow freely to the most productive areas of the economy, workers are employed in better, higher quality jobs with higher wages. While there are inevitable short-term transition costs in some sectors of the economy, the long-term benefits of free trade for all far outweigh such costs.
Thus, as you have seen in earlier section, proponents of free trade suggest several sources of gains from trade. First, as the market potentially served by firms expands from a national to a world market, there are gains associated with declining per unit production costs (economies of scale). Asecond source of gains results from the reduction in the monopoly power- of domestic firms.
Domestic firms, facing more pressure from foreign competitors, are forced to produce the output demanded by cdnsumers at the lowest possible cost. Third is the gain to consumers from increased product variety and lower prices. Generally speaking, the gains from trade result from the increase in competi- tive pressures as the domestic economy becomes less insulated from the world economy. Fourth, when trade barriers are reduced, exports increase and they provide additional avenues for employment and scope for poverty-reduction. Fifth, there is the classical argument from the time of Smith and Ricardo regarding efficient allocation of resources. Moreover, it has also been argued that protection to industries is not costless. For instance, it requires resources from other industries; hence, output in other domestic industries is reduced. Industries might also be less efficient and
uncompetitive due to higher cost of imported inputs used in their production on account of high import tariffs. Since protected industries tend to produce at higher cost, consumers are subjected to high-priced products. Not only that they lose due to lesser consumption of costly protected goods but also consume less of other goods whose prices rise due to their lower production.
It was against this backdrop that the Uruguay Round of the GATT negotiations gained momentum and a new World Trade Organisation came into being in 1995. It envisaged laying down the foundations of a freer trade regime at the multilateral level with the commitment from its members to liberalise trade and other trade-related economic activities. The free trade proponents made different estimates of gains from multilateral liberalisation. As per one estimate, under the WTO, a complete dismantling of existing tariffs on imports worldwide could increase world economic output by approximately 3 per cent. In monetary terms, that amounted to the equivalent of US$1.2 trillion boost to the world economy. It was further argued that the developing countries would gain the most.
Despite this, many of these countries still place protective andor revenue tariffs on foreign products to protect some favoured or politically influential industries, or to reduce the taxation demands on their internal domestic manufacturing, making their products more competitive. The elimination of these tariffs remains a contentious political and diplomatic issue. China and Japan have been accused of protectionist policies that peg their currencies to the dollar and, thus, set ptices of their exports lower than they would be if the market determined the relative prices of each currency. However, the theoretical arguments and the empirical estimates have been contested by those who do not consider free trade as welfare-inducing. Critics argue that the very proponents of free trade actually practise protectionist policies.