Beneficial Externalities:
The example of industry supplying smallpox vaccinations is assumed to be selling in a competitive market may be cited to appreciate the efforts of positive or benefited externality. See that the marginal private benefit of getting the vaccination is less than the marginal social or public benefit by the amount of the external benefit, i.e., the fact that if one person gets the vaccination, others are less likely to get the smallpox even if they themselves are not vaccinated. Figure below shows the effects of a positive or beneficial externality. The marginal external benefit of getting a smallpox shot is represented by the vertical distance between the two demand curves. Assume that there are no external costs, so that social cost equals individual cost.
If consumers only take into account their own private benefits from getting vaccinations, the market will end up at price Pp and quantity as before, instead of the more efficient price P, and quantity a. These latter price quantity combination reflects the idea that the marginal social benefit should equal the marginal social cost, i.e., production should be increased as long as the marginal social benefit exceeds the marginal social cost. The result in an unfettered market is ineflcient since at the quantity Qp, the social benefit is greater than the societal cost. So the society as a whole would be better off if more goods had been produced. The problem is that people are buying too few vaccinations.
The issue of external benefits is related to of public goods, i.e., goods where it is difficult, if not impossible, to exclude people from benefits.